Who benefits from the retrospective vote? Bringing in new parties

被引:0
|
作者
Bochsler, Daniel [1 ,2 ]
Haenni, Miriam [3 ]
机构
[1] Cent European Univ CEU, Nationalism Studies & Polit Sci Dept, Vienna, Austria
[2] Univ Belgrade, Fac Polit Sci, Belgrade, Serbia
[3] Swiss Fed Univ Vocat Educ & Training, Res & Dev Div, Zollikofen, Switzerland
基金
瑞士国家科学基金会;
关键词
New parties; corruption; retrospective voting; economic voting; electoral competition; ELECTORAL CONSEQUENCES; ECONOMIC-CRISIS; SYSTEM VOLATILITY; CORRUPTION; SUPPORT; EUROPE; CHOICE; RISE; INFORMATION; ATTITUDES;
D O I
10.1080/01402382.2022.2145743
中图分类号
D0 [政治学、政治理论];
学科分类号
0302 ; 030201 ;
摘要
Democracies across the world have experienced the rise of new political parties. The dominant view of the model of (retrospective) economic voting implicitly assumes that the main beneficiary of electoral change is the established opposition. However, the rise of new political parties affects how we think of retrospective (economic) voting. This article presents a more nuanced picture of electoral change and considers when electoral turnover benefits established opposition parties, and when new political parties. The theoretical model introduces different macro-economic and macro-political motives for electoral turnover. Using a novel dataset on electoral change, covering 59 democracies worldwide, it is found that high levels of corruption discredit the entire political establishment, and promote the rise of new parties. The effect of economic hardship is more nuanced. Low economic growth mainly benefits the established opposition because voters look for an established alternative within the political system. Rising unemployment, by contrast, promotes the rise of new parties.
引用
收藏
页码:303 / 328
页数:26
相关论文
共 50 条